Usuario:Luis.cea.hdz/el otro raro

De Wikipedia, la enciclopedia libre

El señoreaje también escrito como seigniorage, seignorage o seigneurage (del viejo término en frances seigneuriage "derecho del señor a acuñar moneda") hace referencia a la diferencia entre el valor del dinero y el costo de producirlo y distribuirlo. El término puede ser aplicado de las siguientes maneras:

  • Señoreaje derivado de los metales-monedas metálicas- es un impuesto añadido al precio total de una moneda (contenido metálico y costos de producción) que un cliente de la casa de moneda tiene que pagar; este dinero se manda al área política del estado soberano.[1]
  • Señoreaje derivado de las notas, el cual es indirecto; éste se refiere a la diferencia entre los intereses ganados en los instrumentos adquiridos a cambio de notas del banco y los costos de prducción y distribución de estas notas.[2]

El término también aplica al señoreaje monetario, en donde los instrumentos publicados por el estado son intercambiados por nuevas notas de la casa de moneda expedidas por el banco central, lo cual permite al estado prestar sin la necesidad de pagar.[3]​ Sin embargo, el señoreaje monetario se refiere al ingreso soberano obtenido a través de la monetización de la deuda rutinaria, la cual incluye el incremento de la oferta del dinero durante el crecimiento del PIB y el cumplimiento de los objetivos de tasas de inflación. El señoreaje es una buena fuente fuente de ingresos para una gran cantidad de gobiernos.

Ejemplos[editar]

Escenario A[editar]

Una persona tiene una onza de oro, intercambia ésta por un certificado de oro emitido por el gobierno (la cual prevé el pago de 1 onza de oro); esta persona mantiene el certificado por un año y después pide el repago de su oro. Esta persona termina con la misma cantidad de oro que tenía en el inicio de la operación; por lo tanto no existe el señoreaje.

Escenario B[editar]

En lugar de emitir certificados de oro, el gobierno convierte el oro en moneda a una tasa de mercado a través de la impresión de papel. Una persona cambia una libra de oro por su valor en moneda; esta persona mantiene su dinero por un año y después busca cambiar su dinero por oro en el valor del mercado. Si el valor relativo de la moneda contra el oro ha cambiado durante el tiempo que ocurrió, el cambio provocará que la persona obtenga cantidades mayores o inferiores de oro. (Asumiendo que el valor de compra de una onza de oro se mantiene fijo en el año).

Si el valor de la moneda relativa al dinero ha decrecido, la persona recibe menos que una libra; provocando señeoraje.

Si el valor de la moneda relativa al dinero ha incrementado, la persona recibe más que una libra; el señeoraje no existe.

El señeoraje entonces es el retorno positivo de emitir notas y monedas o dinero en circulación.

El contrario del "costo de acarreo" no está considerado como una forma de señeoraje.

Señeoraje ordinario[editar]

El señeoraje ordinario es solamente un préstamo sin intereses (por ejemplo de oro) al emisor de la moneda. Cuando la divisa está desgastada, el emisor la recompra a precio nomibal, de este modo balancea exactamente el ingreso recibido cuando ésta fue puesta en circulación sin ningún monto adicional por el valor de intereses de lo que el emisor recibió.

Históricamente, el señeoraje fue la utilidad resultante de la producción de monedas. La plata y el oro fueron mezclados con una base de metales para poder generar monedas durables. Por este motivo, la libra esterlina se componía de 92.5% plata pura; el metal base añadido para el resto del porcentaje de la moneda era la utilidad de la casa de moneda ya que ésta cobraba a la libra a precio total de plata pura y ganaba el monto del metal base menos los gastos para que éste pudiera ser añadido a las moneda. Las monedas de oro de USA antes de 1933 fueron hechas de 90% oro y 10% cobre.

Historically, seigniorage was the profit resulting from producing coins. Silver and gold were mixed with base metals to make durable coins. Thus the British "sterling" was 92.5% pure silver; the base metal added (and thus the pure silver retained by the government mint) was (less costs) the profit, the seigniorage. USA gold coins before 1933 were made from 90% gold and 10% copper. To make up for the lack of gold the coins are over-weighted. A one-ounce Gold American Eagle will have as much of the alloy as is needed to contain a total of one ounce of gold which will be over one ounce. Seigniorage is earned by selling the coins above the melt value in exchange for guaranteeing the weight of the coin.

Currently, under the rules governing monetary operations of major central banks (including the central bank of the USA), seigniorage on bank notes is simply defined as the interest payments received by central banks on the total amount of currency issued. This usually takes the form of interest payments on treasury bonds purchased by central banks, putting more dollars into circulation. However, if the currency is collected, or is otherwise taken permanently out of circulation, the back end of the deal never occurs (that is, the currency is never returned to the central bank). Thus the issuer of the currency keeps the whole seigniorage profit, by not having to buy worn out issued currency back at face value.

Solvency constraints of central banks[editar]

The solvency constraint of the standard central bank only requires that the present discounted value of its net non-monetary liabilities (separate from its monetary liabilities accrued through seigniorage attempts) be zero or negative in the long run. Its monetary liabilities are liabilities only in name, as they are irredeemable: the holder of base money cannot insist at any time on the redemption of a given amount of base money into anything else other than the same amount of itself (base money) – unless, of course, the holder of said base money is another central bank reclaiming the value of its original interest-free loan.

Seigniorage as a tax[editar]

Some economists regarded seigniorage as a form of inflation tax, redistributing real resources to the currency issuer. Issuing new currency, rather than collecting taxes paid out of the existing money stock, is then considered in effect a tax that falls on those who hold the existing currency.[4]Inflation of the money supply in the long run may cause, and ceteris paribus will cause, a general rise in prices due to the reduced purchasing power of the currency.

This is one reason offered in support of free banking, a gold or silver standard, or at a minimum the reduction of political control over central banks. The latter could then take as their primary objective ensuring a stable value of currency by controlling monetary expansion and thus limiting inflation. Independence from government is required to reach this aim – indeed, it is well known in economic literature that governments face a conflict of interest in this regard[cita requerida]. In fact, "hard money" advocates argue that central banks have utterly failed to obtain the objective of a stable currency. Under the gold standard, for example, the price level in both England and the US remained relatively stable over hundreds of years, though with some protracted periods of deflation[cita requerida]. Since the US Federal Reserve was formed in 1913, however, the US dollar has fallen to barely a twentieth of its former value through the consistently inflationary policies of the bank. Economists counter that deflation is hard to control once it sets in and its effects are much more damaging than modest, consistent inflation.

Banks or governments relying heavily on seigniorage and fractional reserve sources of revenue can find it counterproductive.[5]Rational expectations of inflation take into account a bank's seigniorage strategy, and inflationary expectations can maintain high inflation. Instead of accruing seigniorage from fiat money and credit, most governments opt to raise revenue primarily through formal taxation and other means.

Today[editar]

The "50 State" series of quarters (25-cent coins) was launched in the U.S. in 1999. The U.S. government planned on a large number of people collecting each new quarter as it rolled out of the U.S. Mint, thus taking the pieces out of circulation.[6]​ Each set of quarters is worth $14.00 (a complete set includes quarters for all fifty states, the five U.S. territories, and the District of Columbia). Since it costs the Mint about five cents for each 25-cent piece it produces, the government made a profit whenever someone "bought" a coin.[7]​ The U.S. Treasury estimates that it has earned about US$6.3 billion in seigniorage from the quarters over the course of the entire program.[8]

In some cases, national mints report the amount of seigniorage provided to their respective governments; for example, the Royal Canadian Mint reported that in 2006 it generated $C93 million in seigniorage for the Government of Canada.[9]​ The U.S. government, the largest beneficiary of seignorage, earned approximately $25 billion annually as of 2000.[10]​ For coinage only, seigniorage accruing to the U.S. Treasury per dollar issued for the fiscal year 2011 was 45 cents.[11]

Occasionally, central banks have introduced limited quantities of higher-valued banknotes in unusual denominations, with the intention of these notes being collected. The denomination chosen will usually coincide with an anniversary of national significance. However, the potential seigniorage that can be earned from such printings has proven to be limited, since the unusual denomination makes the notes more difficult to circulate and only a relatively small number of people are willing to collect higher-valued notes.

According to some reports, over half of Zimbabwe governmental revenue in 2008 was seigniorage.[12]​ Zimbabwe has experienced hyperinflation (see Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe), with the annualized rate at about 24,000% in July 2008 (prices doubling every 46 days).[13]

Overseas circulation[editar]

A very profitable type of seignorage is from the international circulation of banknotes. While the cost of printing banknotes is minimal, the foreign entity must provide goods and services at the face value of the note to obtain it. The banknote is retained because the entity values it as a store of value because of mistrust of the local currency.

Overseas circulation is intimately tied in with large value banknotes. One purpose of using foreign currency is for store of value, but another is efficiency of private transactions, some of which are illegal.

American currency has been circulating globally for most of the 20th century. Certainly in World War II, the amount of currency in circulation was increased several fold. However, the modern era of huge printings of the United States one hundred-dollar bill started with the fall of the Soviet Union in 1991. Production was quadrupled with the first ever trillion dollar printing of this bill. As of the end of 2008, U.S. currency in circulation with the public amounted to $824 billion and 76% of the currency supply was in the form of $100 denomination banknotes, amounting to twenty $100 bills per U.S. citizen.[14]​ Over the past decade there has been considerable controversy concerning the amount of U.S. currency circulating abroad. Porter and Judson[15]​ have claimed that in the mid nineties between 53 and 67 percent of U.S. currency was overseas, whereas Feige’s[16]​ estimates suggested a figure closer to 40 percent abroad. Most recently, Goldberg[17]​ writing in a New York Federal Reserve publication asserted that “about 65 percent ($580 billion) of all banknotes are in circulation outside of the country. However, these assertions are contradicted by the Federal Reserve Board of Governors Flow of Funds statistics[18]​ which show that at the end of March 2009, only $313 billion (36.7 percent) of U.S. currency was held abroad. Feige calculates that since 1964, "the cumulative seigniorage earnings accruing to the U.S. by virtue of the currency held by foreigners amounted to $167–$185 billion and over the past two decades seigniorage revenues from foreigners have averaged $6–$7 billion dollars per year".

The American $100 bill has some competition, primarily from the €500 note. The larger value of the banknote makes it easier to transport larger amounts of money. As an example, $1 million in currency in $100 bills weighs 22 pounds, if, say, you were to carry it on board an airplane. It is difficult to carry this much money without a briefcase and some physical security. Since it is contrary to Title 26 of the United States Code (U.S.Tax Code) to carry more than $10,000 without reporting it (31 USC 5311), this is unlikely to pass security unnoticed. The same amount in €500 notes would weigh less than three pounds, and it could probably be dispersed in clothing and in luggage without attracting attention or alerting a security device. For many illegal operations, the problem of transporting currency is more difficult than transporting cocaine because of the size and weight of the currency. The ease of transporting banknotes makes the euro very attractive to Latin American drug cartels.[19]

The Swiss 1000 franc note is probably the only other banknote that is in circulation outside of its home country. It is worth slightly more than US$1000. However, to the non-Swiss it doesn't provide a significant advantage over the €500 note as there are 20 times as many of the €500 note circulating and they are more widely recognized. As a reserve currency it is roughly 0.1% of the currency composition of official foreign exchange reserves.

Governments differ radically in their issuance of large banknotes. As of August 2009, the number of 1000 Swiss franc notes circulating was over three times the population of Switzerland. In comparison, the number of £50 banknotes circulating is slightly less than three times the population of the United Kingdom. But the 1000 franc note is worth roughly £600. The British government has traditionally been wary of large banknotes since the counterfeiting Operation Bernhard in World War II which caused the Bank of England to withdraw all notes larger than £5 from circulation, and not reintroduce other denominations until the early 1960s (£10), 1970 (£20) and March 20, 1981 (£50).

The American treasury considered re-issuing a US$500 banknote when the euro banknotes began circulating. There was concern that the high value banknotes would provide competition. However, after recognition that the $500 banknote would provide a huge advantage to worldwide criminal operations and dictatorships, the decision was made not to pursue this option.[cita requerida]

See also[editar]

Money

References[editar]

  1. http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/QR/QR2142.pdf
  2. Bank of Canada (March 2012). «Backgrounders: Seigniorage». Consultado el 2 January 2013. 
  3. Neumann, Manfred J.M. «Seigniorage in the United How Much Does the U.S. Government Make from Money Production?». Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Consultado el 17 June 2014. 
  4. Brian Snowdon and Howard Vane, An Encyclopedia of Macroeconomics, p. 246
  5. Tara McIndoe-Calder, Hyperinflation in Zimbabwe: Money Demand, Seigniorage and Aid shocks, Central Bank of Ireland; University of Dublin - Institute for International Integration Studies, May 1, 2009
  6. United States Mint 50 State Quarters® Design Use Policy, Retrieved December 5, 2013
  7. «Frequently Asked Questions». The 50 State Quarters Program of the United States Mint. United States Mint. Archivado desde el original el 13 de julio de 2007. Consultado el 18 de octubre de 2009. 
  8. http://news.coinupdate.com/state-quarters-program-seigniorage-0133/
  9. Annual Report (2006), Royal Canadian Mint, p. 4
  10. http://banking.senate.gov/docs/reports/dollar.htm
  11. United States Mint FY 2013 President’s Budget Submission United States Treasury
  12. Gerson, Michael (20 de febrero de 2008). «Dying Silently In Zimbabwe». The Washington Post. Consultado el 29 de mayo de 2009. 
  13. http://www.newzimbabwe.com/pages/inflation180.17386.html
  14. Edgar L. Feige "New estimates of overseas U.S. currency holdings, the Underground economy and the "Tax Gap" Forthcoming in Crime, Law and Social Change. https://ideas.repec.org/p/pra/mprapa/19564.html
  15. Porter and Judson, 1996, R. D. Porter and R. A. Judson, The location of U.S. currency: How much is abroad? Federal Reserve Bulletin 82 (1996), pp. 883–903
  16. Feige, 1997, E. L. Feige, Revised estimates of the underground economy: Implications of U.S. currency held abroad, in O. Lippert and M. Walker (ed.) The Underground economy: Global evidence of its size and impact. (1997), pp. 151–208. https://ideas.repec.org/p/pra/mprapa/13805.html
  17. Goldberg, 2010, L. S. Goldberg, Is the International Role of the Dollar Changing? Federal Reserve Bank Of New York, Current Issues in Economics and Finance, 16(1) (2010) pp. 1–7.
  18. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/ and See:Edgar L. Feige "New estimates of overseas U.S. currency holdings, the Underground economy and the "Tax Gap" https://ideas.repec.org/p/pra/mprapa/19564.html
  19. «Latin American drug cartels find home in West Africa». CNN. September 21, 2009. 

Further reading[editar]

External links[editar]